In one of my recent posts I pointed out that:
"The
causes of the crisis have been neither the public sector deficit nor the
failure to implement "structural reforms" ... (contrarily) both: rising private debt levels and the lack of
prudence and efficiency on the part of the creditors that caused this situation
are at the root of the crisis in Europe.
In
such circumstances, policies of
"internal devaluation" offer no solution but rather create a vicious
circle of increasing austerity. Yet, believing that the solution to the crisis faced by the countries of
Europe is simply a matter of revoking the austerity measures and promoting
expansionary policies is just a dream.
The
existence of the euro –
which means countries have neither their own currency nor the instruments
needed for implementing their own sovereign economic policy – make this impossible.
In
fact, an expansionary policy in the
peripheral countries, in a situation of fixed exchange rates (because of
the existence of the euro), would result in increasing problems of current account imbalances.
Bearing
in mind that the current crisis is not a public debt crisis but one of external
private debt, it seems logical that the
priority of the economic policy should strive for equilibrium in the balance of
payments (the so-called "External Compact") rather than equilibrium in the public sector
balances (which is what the "Fiscal Compact" has tried to do,
without much success). In fact, the proposal that international trade ought to
be balanced, besides being logical, is not new: it was proposed by Keynes at
Bretton Woods and it is also what Meade later proposed to ensure that economic
integration might work."
Furthermore, and "as Paul De Grauwe has pointed out, the
internal devaluation (and especially “wage devaluation”) in the
peripheral countries of the euro zone, and in Spain in particular, has been very intense. Moreover, a
comparison with the countries at the core shows that the burden of the
adjustments to improve the imbalances in the euro zone between creditor and
debtor states has been highly asymmetric, with the peripheral countries being
the ones that have had to suffer almost exclusively these adjustments, as
has happened in other fixed exchange rate regimes, including that of Bretton
Woods and the European Monetary System. Some
believed that the European Monetary Union and the euro would change this
behaviour, but it has not worked out like that: the adjustment process has been
as asymmetric as in the other fixed exchange rate regimes."
So, one of the main challenges for
the Spanish economy to be able to have a solid, strong and powerful recovery
was "the problems that represents the existence of the euro and concretely
the loss of importance of industry and manufacturing in a context of lower
growth and loss of competitiveness.".
Now we will analyze more concretely
these problems.
It can be observed that, during the period of
expansion that began in the Spanish economy from the mid 80s of last century,
there has been growth rates -in annual cumulated average growth rate- higher
before (1986-1998) than after the implementation of the euro (1999-2007).
Moreover, after the implementation of the euro there
is a loss of weight of both the industrial production and the manufacturing
production in France, Italy and Spain, and contrarily it has increased in
Germany, especially after the outbreak of the crisis.
Moreover, the use of the
installed industrial capacity is systematically lower in Spain and Italy than
in France and Germany as well as in the EU and the euro area.
Finally, the evolution of competitiveness (measured by the Real Effective
Exchange Rate) in Spain has been
negative, in absolute terms and more than the euro area in relative terms, in 1994-98 and in 1999-2007 while in
both periods in Germany it was positive. From
the onset of the crisis the competitiveness has improved but more in Germany
and especially in the euro area than in Spain.
The Real Effective Exchange Rate
(REER) calculated by the Bank of International Settlements (BIS), which are
internationally accepted measures of international competitiveness, are
compiled by adjusting the nominal exchange rates (nominal parity among
currencies) by the relative inflation rates and other production costs.
Then, if the real effective exchange rate rises for a
nation it signals a loss in its international competitiveness. Conversely, if
the real effective exchange rate falls it signals a gain in its international
competitiveness.
Cap comentari:
Publica un comentari a l'entrada